Today’s objectives
Why This Topic is Important
serfdom has left indelible imprint on Russian economy, institutions
economic legacy of serfdom:
institutional legacy of serfdom:
relevance today:
Serf and Lord
Varieties of Forced Labor
Slavery (rabstvo)
Indentured Service (kholopstvo)
Kholopy
Varieties of Forced Labor
Serfdom (krepostnoye pravo)
Serfs
Between 1263 (start of Grand Duchy) and 1721 (start of Empire), Muscovite Russia expanded its territory through war 77 times.
These wars created two problems:
War Makes the State
war demands institutions that are conducive to state formation:
- standing army
- tax revenues (to support army)
- bureaucracy (to raise revenues)
but Muscovy too underdeveloped to support army through taxes
Solution: create landed army
Battle for Kazan
Warriors Become Feudal Lords
Problem: not enough peasants
Solution: serfdom
Peasants Moving
Simple production function, with one factor (Labor).
Declining returns to scale.
Take the derivative, and we get the marginal product of labor.
This represents how much each additional laborer contributes.
Suppose there are \(L_1\) peasants living on this plot of land.
We’ll assume that labor is scarce, so \(L_1\) is pretty small.
Each of the \(L_1\) peasants receives market wage \(W_1\).
This wage depends on the peasant’s contribution to productivity.
Let \(s\) denote level of wages needed for basic subsistence.
Suppose \(W_1\) is above subsistence wage \(s\).
Landlord receives rent from the peasants.
Rent is equivalent to what the peasants produce, minus their wages.
Peasant get to keep the remaining surplus (to spend/invest/save).
Surplus is what they earn, minus what they spend on subsistence.
Now suppose there is population growth, from \(L_1\) to \(L_2\).
Peasants’ market wages fall from \(W_1\) to \(W_2\), below subsistence!
Landlord wins (more tenants \(\to\) more rents).
Peasants lose (lower wages \(\to\) less/no surplus).
Now suppose a second plot of land opens up (Land B).
Let’s assume this new land is of equal size and quality as Land A.
Land A is overpopulated, wages are low.
Land B is underpopulated, wages are high (\(L_A\)\(>\)\(L_B\), \(W_A\)\(<\)\(W_B\)).
Peasants from Land A begin to migrate to Land B, until population levels reach equilibrium (\(L_A^{eq}\), \(L_B^{eq}\)), wages are same (\(W_A^{eq}\)\(=\)\(W_B^{eq}\)).
This is good for peasants from Land A.
Migration raises their rents above subsistence. Surplus is back!
But this is bad for landlord A.
Out-migration results in fewer tenants and fewer rents.
What are landlord A’s options?
(a) do nothing, lose money; (b) lobby government to allow serfdom.
Serfdom \(=\)
migration restriction \(+\) surplus extraction
Land/labor ratio and serfdom
Why does territorial expansion make serfdom more appealing?
Why not just stop expanding?
Serfs
Russia’s External Threat Environment (1450-1800)
Belligerent | Conflicts | Start | End |
---|---|---|---|
Kazan | 3 | 1467 | 1487 |
Novgorod | 3 | 1471 | 1570 |
Livonia | 1 | 1477 | 1478 |
Lithuania | 2 | 1487 | 1503 |
Sweden | 21 | 1495 | 1742 |
Crimean Khanate | 2 | 1571 | 1572 |
Poland | 23 | 1579 | 1794 |
Cossacks | 26 | 1649 | 1774 |
Streltsy | 2 | 1682 | 1698 |
Ottoman Empire | 21 | 1711 | 1791 |
Finland | 1 | 1714 | 1714 |
Bashkirs | 1 | 1755 | 1755 |
Prussia | 10 | 1757 | 1760 |
Polish Confederates | 1 | 1768 | 1768 |
France | 9 | 1799 | 1799 |
Why Did Serfdom Decline?
Tsar Alexander II abolished serfdom in 1861
at the time, 45% of peasants (38% of total pop) were serfs
but the state had created pathways out of serfdom before:
Why did the state end serfdom?
Were the interests of state and landlords always aligned?
Emancipation
Meanwhile, in Europe…
Why was Russia different? Was it?
Would Muscovy have kept expanding if it never allowed serfdom?
England
NEXT MEETING
Colonial Expansion and an Unstable Frontier (Tu, Sep. 12)